找回密码
 立即注册
搜索
热搜: 活动 交友 discuz
查看: 44|回复: 0

芒格十大演讲第六讲:Investment Practices of Leading Charitable Foundations.

[复制链接]

68

主题

0

回帖

214

积分

积分
214
发表于 2021-6-7 14:24:22 | 显示全部楼层 |阅读模式
Charlie Munger on Institutional Funds Management
  Speech of Charles T. Munger, Vice Chair, Berkshire Hathaway, at Miramar Sheraton
  Hotel, Santa Monica, CA, on October 14, 1998, to a meeting of the Foundation Financial
  Officers Group sponsored by The Conrad Hilton Foundation, The Amateur Athletic
  Foundation, The J. Paul Getty Trust, and Rio Hondo Memorial Foundation. The speech is
  reproduced here with Mr. Munger's permission.
  Investment Practices of Leading Charitable Foundations.
  I am speaking here today because my friend, John Argue, asked me. And John well knew
  that I, who, unlike many other speakers on your agenda, have nothing to sell any of you,
  would be irreverent about much current investment practice in large institutions,
  including charitable foundations. Therefore any hostility my talk will cause should be
  directed at John Argue who comes from the legal profession and may even enjoy it.
  It was long the norm at large charitable foundations to invest mostly in unleveraged,
  marketable, domestic securities, mostly equities. The equities were selected by one or a
  very few investment counselling organizations. But in recent years there has been a drift
  toward more complexity. Some foundations, following the lead of institutions like Yale,
  have tried to become much better versions of Bernie Cornfeld's "fund of funds." This is
  an amazing development. Few would have predicted that, long after Cornfeld's fall into
  disgrace, leading universities would be leading foundations into Cornfeld's system.
  Now, in some foundations, there are not few but many investment counselors, chosen by
  an additional layer of consultants who are hired to decide which investment counselors
  are best, help in allocating funds to various categories, make sure that foreign securities
  are not neglected in favor of domestic securities, check validity of claimed investment
  records, insure that claimed investment styles are scrupulously followed, and help
  augment an already large diversification in a way that conforms to the latest notions of
  corporate finance professors about volatility and "beta."
  But even with this amazingly active, would-be-polymathic new layer of consultantchoosing
  consultants, the individual investment counselors, in picking common stocks,
  still rely to a considerable extent on a third layer of consultants. The third layer consists
  of the security analysts employed by investment banks. These security analysts receive
  enormous salaries, sometimes set in seven figures after bidding wars. The hiring
  investment banks recoup these salaries from two sources: (1) commissions and trading
  spreads born by security buyers (some of which are rebated as "soft dollars" to money
  managers), plus (2) investment banking charges paid by corporations which appreciate
  the enthusiastic way their securities are being recommended by the security analysts.
  There is one thing sure about all this complexity including its touches of behavior lacking
  the full punctilio of honor. Even when nothing but unleveraged stock-picking is involved,
  the total cost of all the investment management, plus the frictional costs of fairly often
  getting in and out of many large investment positions, can easily reach 3% of foundation
  net worth per annum if foundations, urged on by consultants, add new activity, year after
  year. This full cost doesn't show up in conventional accounting. But that is because
  accounting has limitations and not because the full cost isn't present.
  Next, we come to time for a little arithmetic: it is one thing each year to pay the croupiers
  3% of starting wealth when the average foundation is enjoying a real return, say, of 17%
  before the croupiers' take. But it is not written in the stars that foundations will always
  gain 17% gross, a common result in recent years. And if the average annual gross real
  return from indexed investment in equities goes back, say, to 5% over some long future
  period, and the croupiers' take turns out to remain the waste it has always been, even for
  the average intelligent player, then the average intelligent foundation will be in a
  prolonged, uncomfortable, shrinking mode. After all, 5% minus 3% minus 5% in
  donations leaves an annual shrinkage of 3%.
  All the equity investors, in total, will surely bear a performance disadvantage per annum
  equal to the total croupiers' costs they have jointly elected to bear. This is an unescapable
  fact of life. And it is also unescapable that exactly half of the investors will get a result
  below the median result after the croupiers' take, which median result may well be
  somewhere between unexciting and lousy.
  Human nature being what it is, most people assume away worries like those I raise. After
  all, five centuries before Christ Demosthenes noted that: "What a man wishes, he will
  believe." And in self appraisals of prospects and talents it is the norm, as Demosthenes
  predicted, for people to be ridiculously over-optimistic. For instance, a careful survey in
  Sweden showed that 90% of automobile drivers considered themselves above average.
  And people who are successfully selling something, as investment counselors do, make
  Swedish drivers sound like depressives. Virtually every investment expert's public
  assessment is that he is above average, no matter what is the evidence to the contrary.
  But, you may think, my foundation, at least, will be above average. It is well endowed,
  hires the best, and considers all investment issues at length and with objective
  professionalism. And to this I respond that an excess of what seems like professionalism
  will often hurt you horribly — precisely because the careful procedures themselves often
  lead to overconfidence in their outcome.
  General Motors recently made just such a mistake, and it was a lollapalooza. Using fancy
  consumer surveys, its excess of professionalism, it concluded not to put a fourth door in a
  truck designed to serve also as the equivalent of a comfortable five-passenger car. Its
  competitors, more basic, had actually seen five people enter and exit cars. Moreover they
  had noticed that people were used to four doors in a comfortable five-passenger car and
  that biological creatures ordinarily prefer effort minimization in routine activies and don't
  like removals of long-enjoyed benefits. There are only two words that come instantly to
  mind in reviewing General Motors horrible decision, which has blown many hundreds of
  millions of dollars. And one of those words is: "oops."
  Similarly, the hedge fund known as "Long Term Capital Management" recently
  collapsed, through overconfidence in its highly leveraged methods, despite I.Qs. of its
  principals that must have averaged 160. Smart, hard-working people aren't exempted
  from professional disasters from overconfidence. Often, they just go around in the more
  difficult voyages they choose, relying on their self-appraisals that they have superior
  talents and methods.
  It is, of course, irritating that extra care in thinking is not all good but also introduces
  extra error. But most good things have undesired "side effects," and thinking is no
  exception. The best defense is that of the best physicists, who systematically criticize
  themselves to an extreme degree, using a mindset described by Nobel Laureate Richard
  Feynman as follows: "The first principle is that you must not fool yourself and you're the
  easiest person to fool."
  But suppose that an abnormally realistic foundation, thinking like Feynman, fears a poor
  future investment outcome because it is unwilling to assume that its unleveraged equities
  will outperform equity indexes, minus all investment costs, merely because the
  foundation has adopted the approach of becoming a "fund of funds," with much
  investment turnover and layers of consultants that consider themselves above average.
  What are this fearful foundation's options as it seeks improved prospects?
  There are at least three modern choices:
  1. The foundation can both dispense with its consultants and reduce its investment
  turnover as it changes to indexed investment in equities.
  2. The foundation can follow the example of Berkshire Hathaway, and thus get total
  annual croupier costs below 1/10 of 1% of principal per annum, by investing with
  virtually total passivity in a very few much-admired domestic corporations. And there
  is no reason why some outside advice can't be used in this process. All the fee payor
  has to do is suitably control the high talent in investment counseling organizations so
  that the servant becomes the useful tool of its master, instead of serving itself under the
  perverse incentives of a sort of Mad Hatter's tea party.
  3. The foundation can supplement unleveraged investment in marketable equities with
  investment in limited partnerships that do some combination of the following:
  unleveraged investment in high-tech corporations in their infancy; leveraged
  investments in corporate buy-outs, leveraged relative value trades in equities, and
  leveraged convergence trades and other exotic trades in all kinds of securities and
  derivatives.
  For the obvious reasons given by purveyors of indexed equities, I think choice (1),
  indexing, is a wiser choice for the average foundation than what it is now doing in
  unleveraged equity investment. And particularly so as its present total croupier costs
  exceed 1% of principal per annum. Indexing can't work well forever if almost everybody
  turns to it. But it will work all right for a long time.
  Choice (3), investment in fancy limited partnerships, is largely beyond the scope of this
  talk. I will only say that the Munger Foundation does not so invest, and briefly mention
  two considerations bearing on "LBO" funds.
  The first consideration bearing on LBO funds is that buying 100% of corporations with
  much financial leverage and two layers of promotional carry (one for the management
  and one for the general partners in the LBO fund) is no sure thing to outperform equity
  indexes in the future if equity indexes perform poorly in the future. In substance, a LBO
  fund is a better way of buying equivalents of marketable equities on margin, and the debt
  could prove disastrous if future marketable equity performance is bad. And particularly
  so if the bad performance comes from generally bad business conditions.
  The second consideration is increasing competition for LBO candidates. For instance, if
  the LBO candidates are good service corporations, General Electric can now buy more
  than $10 billion worth per year in GE's credit corporation, with 100% debt financing at
  an interest rate only slightly higher than the U.S. Government is paying. This sort of thing
  is not ordinary competition, but supercompetition. And there are now very many LBO
  funds, both large and small, mostly awash in money and with general partners highly
  incentivized to buy something. In addition there is increased buying competition from
  corporations other than GE, using some combination of debt and equity.
  In short, in the LBO field, there is a buried covariance with marketable equities —
  toward disaster in generally bad business conditions — and competition is now extreme.
  Given time limitation, I can say no more about limited partnerships, one of which I once
  ran. This leaves for extensive discussion only foundation choice (2), more imitation of
  the investment practices of Berkshire Hathaway in maintaining marketable equity
  portfolios with virtually zero turnover and with only a very few stocks chosen. This
  brings us to the question of how much investment diversification is desirable at
  foundations.
  I have more than skepticism regarding the orthodox view that huge diversification is a
  must for those wise enough so that indexation is not the logical mode for equity
  investment. I think the orthodox view is grossly mistaken.
  In the United States, a person or institution with almost all wealth invested, long term, in
  just three fine domestic corporations is securely rich. And why should such an owner care
  if at any time most other investors are faring somewhat better or worse. And particularly
  so when he rationally believes, like Berkshire, that his long-term results will be superior
  by reason of his lower costs, required emphasis on long-term effects, and concentration in
  his most preferred choices.
  I go even further. I think it can be a rational choice, in some situations, for a family or a
  foundation to remain 90% concentrated in one equity. Indeed, I hope the Mungers follow
  roughly this course. And I note that the Woodruff foundations have, so far, proven
  extremely wise to retain an approximately 90% concentration in the founder's Coca-Cola
  stock. It would be interesting to calculate just how all American foundations would have
  fared if they had never sold a share of founder's stock. Very many, I think, would now be
  much better off. But, you may say, the diversifiers simply took out insurance against a
  catastrophe that didn't occur. And I reply: there are worse things than some foundation's
  losing relative clout in the world, and rich institutions, like rich individuals, should do a
  lot of self insurance if they want to maximize long-term results.
  Furthermore, all the good in the world is not done by foundation donations. Much more
  good is done through the ordinary business operations of the corporations in which the
  foundations invest. And some corporations do much more good than others in a way that
  gives investors therein better than average long-term prospects do. And I don't consider it
  foolish, stupid, evil, or illegal for a foundation to greatly concentrate investment in what
  it admires or even loves. Indeed, Ben Franklin required just such an investment practice
  for the charitable endowment created by his will.
  One other aspect of Berkshire's equity investment practice deserves comparative mention.
  So far, there has been almost no direct foreign investment at Berkshire and much foreign
  investment at foundations.
  Regarding this divergent history, I wish to say that I agree with Peter Drucker that the
  culture and legal systems of the United States are especially favorable to shareholder
  interests, compared to other interests and compared to most other countries. Indeed, there
  are many other countries where any good going to public shareholders has a very low
  priority and almost every other constituency stands higher in line. This factor, I think is
  underweighed at many investment institutions, probably because it does not easily lead to
  quantitative thinking using modern financial technique. But some important factor doesn't
  lose share of force just because some "expert" can better measure other types of force.
  Generally, I tend to prefer over direct foreign investment Berkshire's practice of
  participating in foreign economies through the likes of Coca-Cola and Gillette.
  To conclude, I will make one controversial prediction and one controversial argument.
  The controversial prediction is that, if some of you make your investment style more like
  Berkshire Hathaway's, in a long-term retrospect you will be unlikely to have cause for
  regret, even if you can't get Warren Buffett to work for nothing. Instead, Berkshire will
  have cause for regret as it faces more intelligent investment competition. But Berkshire
  won't actually regret any disadvantage from your enlightenment. We only want what
  success we can get despite encouraging others to share our general views about reality.
  My controversial argument is an additional consideration weighing against the complex,
  high-cost investment modalities becoming ever more popular at foundations. Even if,
  contrary to my suspicions, such modalities should turn out to work pretty well, most of
  the money-making activity would contain profoundly antisocial effects. This would be so
  because the activity would exacerbate the current, harmful trend in which ever more of
  the nation's ethical young brainpower is attracted into lucrative money-management and
  its attendant modern frictions, as distinguished from work providing much more value to
  others. Money management does not create the right examples. Early Charlie Munger is a
  horrible career model for the young, because not enough was delivered to civilization in
  return for what was wrested from capitalism. And other similar career models are even
  worse.
  Rather than encourage such models, a more constructive choice at foundations is longterm
  investment concentration in a few domestic corporations that are wisely admired.
  Why not thus imitate Ben Franklin? After all, old Ben was very effective in doing public
  good. And he was a pretty good investor, too. Better his model, I think, than Bernie
  Cornfeld's. The choice is plainly yours to make. LJW
  
回复

使用道具 举报

您需要登录后才可以回帖 登录 | 立即注册

本版积分规则

QQ|Archiver|手机版|小黑屋|价值投资商学院 Touzi.MBA

GMT+8, 2025-7-19 05:17 , Processed in 0.109139 second(s), 20 queries .

Powered by Discuz! X3.5

© 2001-2025 Discuz! Team.

快速回复 返回顶部 返回列表